Rebirth of the dot.com

The dot.com business model was built around new technologies and new ways of doing business. Fast-growing companies and their intellectual property were snapped up in mergers and acquisitions at a blistering pace in the boom. Now, many of the purchasers are hoping to shed excess weight.

In steps the newly formed “Venture Buyout” firm Garnett & Helfrich Capital:

Now a pair of Silicon Valley-based venture capitalists have opened an unusual $250 million fund intended to buy and rehabilitate such companies, which Terry Garnett, one of the two founders, calls “the orphaned and the unloved.” (NYTimes)

In many cases, the partners hope to bring original creators back to run the new companies.

“We’ve heard from a number of founders,” Mr. Garnett said, “who told us, ‘Gosh, we sold our business four years ago, and now our baby has been all screwed up and we want it back.’ ”

Garnett & Helfrich provide their own definition of terms:

Ven-ture Buy-out (ven’cher bi’out’) noun. The purchase of a technology business from a parent company, and the subsequent rebuilding of that business into an innovative and profitable enterprise. Involves risk of capital and substantial changes to the business to improve management and operations after acquisition.

No prescription needed for Statins?

NYTimes is reporting that a chloesterol lowering drug will be sold over-the-counter in the UK beginning this summer.

Starting in July, a low dosage of the drug Zocor will be sold over the counter to people at moderate risk of heart disease, a number that could reach 5 million to 10 million. That group includes all men older than 55, as well as men over 45 and women over 55 who smoke, are overweight, have a family history of heart disease or come from the Indian subcontinent, all groups that are at higher risk than the general population.

img007
The US patent for Zocor (simvastatin) is expected to expire in 2006.

Update 5/17/04: US drug makers are working with the FDA to get OTC approval.

A decision is months away, but approval by the Food and Drug Administration could significantly affect the nation’s biggest public health problem, heart disease, and greatly expand sales in the top-selling drug category. (Article)

Googling by the Court

Judicial fact finding is back in vogue this time via Google.

In the United States and abroad, judges are turning to search engines such as Google to check facts, to look up information about companies embroiled in litigation, and to challenge statistics presented by attorneys in court. Dozens of judges have penned opinions describing Google as a valuable–and sometimes crucial–source of knowledge. (Declan McCullagh at CNet News)

Under the Federal Rules of Evidence (Rule 201), this type of judicial notice of facts is only allowed when the accuracy of outside sources “cannot reasonably be questioned.”

Related Book: The Lawyer’s Guide to Fact Finding on the Internet) by Carole Levitt and Mark Rosch has an updated edition with lots of examples.

Written especially for legal professionals, this … edition is a complete, hands-on guide … for conducting efficient research on the Web. Learn the differences between legal research and fact-finding. Discover the distinction between the “visible” and “invisible” Web and how to find information in each. Learn the nuances of search engines in order to formulate strategies for locating the information you need. And read real-world war stories of how Internet data has benefited other legal professionals. (ernietheattorney)

Other: Illustrated patent case law.
(Thanks to Lori Patel, Law.com for the Link)

Today’s Model: University Research => Money

An article in the USA Today presents a handful of anecdotes of universities reaping huge monetary rewards for their research.

The Stanford-Google ties spotlight a growing trend on campuses from California to Florida. More schools are trying to boost revenue by profiting from campus research — a once-taboo practice.

More than 300 universities are mining laboratories and classrooms for discoveries that could become the next Google or anti-cancer drug. That’s up from 25 in 1980.

“They pray that maybe they’ll get the big score,” says Eric G. Campbell, an assistant professor at Harvard Medical School who has studied the trend.

New Theory Supporting the Doctrine of Equivalents

The Doctrine of Equivalents (DOE) has traditionally been justified as a way to overcome language limitations, mistake, and unforeseeability. Ironically, these elements are missing from leading DOE case law.

Michael Meurer and Craig Nard have released a working paper that brings to light a new justification for the DOE. According to Meurer and Nard, a highly skilled and motivated patent attorney / inventor team would not need the doctrine of equivalents. Through thoughtful and clever claim drafting, the team could obtain patents that would directly cover any potential infringers. This thoughtfulness and cleverness, however, will have a large price tag (i.e., many hours for a highly paid patent attorney).

We develop a better explanation of why claim breadth falls short of the maximum breadth allowed by patent law. Our explanation replaces the passive patent attorney depicted in the friction theory with an active inventor and attorney who are capable of responding effectively to the frictions mentioned above. Whether an inventor obtains the broadest permissible claim breadth depends mostly on the talent and effort of the inventor and attorney in identifying what has been enabled. A good attorney predicts the embodiments that could be chosen by infringers and finds appropriate language to draft a suitably broad claim. We call this process claim refinement, and we develop a refinement theory of the doctrine of equivalents.

Because the pricetag associated with patent drafting is so large, Meurer and Nard argue that such a cost will not be socially optimal. The DOE serves to accomodate less-than-perfect claim drafting — thus allowing a better allocation of resources.

3M Reexaminations

Only a select few ex parte reexaminations are filed by patent owners. Often the technology at issue is of particular importance, and the owner hopes to ensure that the patent is valid before pursuing potential infringers.
img004
3M recently filed for reexamination for several patents covering field flattening lenses used in wide screen television (TV) technology. (Nipper). This may be a reaction to the recent patent tussle between Fujitsu and Samsung.

Submarine patent

George Graff and Adam Kraidin have written a concise article for the Washington Legal Foundation that neatly summarizes current law on submarine patents. Submarine patents use successive continuation applications to claim previously disclosed but unclaimed features of an invention many years after the filing of the original application. Ricoh v. Nashua (Fed. Cir. 1999).

Most recently, the Nevada District Court in Symbol Technologies v. Lemelson used a 7-factor test in finding Lemelson’s patents unenforceable.

1. The overall delay between the filing of the application and the issuance of the claims;
2. The initial delay in presenting the claims to the patent office for the first time;
3. Lemelson’s original disclosures were made public in the 1960s, and the original patents based on those disclosures had expired by the early 1980s;
4. Before the asserted claims were filed, numerous articles and patents describing machine vision and bar code scanning had been published, and commercial products had been developed and marketed;
5. Lemelson was aware of the developments in the machine vision and bar code fields, but still delayed the issuance of patents asserting his claims;
6. Lemelson systematically extended the pendency of his applications by sitting on his rights, and sequentially filing one application at a time, so that he could maintain their pendency while waiting for viable commercial systems to be designed and marketed; and
7. Finally, after others had successfully developed and commercially exploited the technology, Lemelson drafted and prosecuted hundreds of new claims in the late 1980s and 1990s specifically worded to cover those commercial systems.

In addition, the Symbol court noted that widespread use of Lemelson’s technology prior to the suit “created adverse intervening private and public rights.”

Richard Epstein and Hatch-Waxman

My former professor, Richard Epstein, has a new working paper with co-author Bruce Kuhlik arguing that the Hatch-Waxman Act represents a “sound compromise” that should not be undercut by pro-generic legislative efforts.

Strong property right protection — as opposed to the compulsory licensing schemes advocated by others . . . should remain the dominant approach in patent law.

We think that Heller and Eisenberg have overstated the case against patent protection at both the theoretical and empirical level. . . . We see no reason to believe that the sole or dominant purpose for [obtaining a patent] is to block innovations by others. Patents themselves are expensive to acquire. The inventor only makes income to the extent that it can assign, license or sell the patent in question.

Epstein & Kuhlik specifically address S.812 (Greater Access to Affordable Pharmaceuticals Act) passed by the Senate in 2002. (Reintroduced here). They argue that the Act’s anti-price-discrimination terms would push the price of patented drugs down to a generic pricing level — effectively repealing the patent.

And, without ample patent protection, no combination of first mover advantages or altruism will generate the capital sums needed [to fund the high cost of pharmaceutical research].

(Thanks to Professor Sampat for the link).

Although not a direct rebuttal, Colman Ragan argues in the most recent Federal Circuit Bar Journal that procedural amendments to Hatch-Waxman will help lower drug prices.

Advice for Future Patent Attorneys

Michael Madison, a professor at Pittsburgh, has provided some good advice for any scientist or engineer hoping to move into the field of patent law:

I have two standard responses: One is: run, don’t walk, away from “law school prep courses.” (How to read cases, outline courses, take exams.) They’re worse than useless. They’re useless and expensive. Two is: Read Shakespeare. Or if not Shakespeare, then read Melville. Dickinson. Ellison. Baldwin. Morrison. Borges. Milosz. Pick a major literary figure–any gender, any genre, any era–and read that person’s works. Be literate, in every sense of that word.

Dr. Quentin Young

My neighbor, Dr. Quentin Young has a letter in today’s Chicago Tribune concerning medicine prices:

We need to negotiate with pharmaceutical firms, demanding that they provide much greater value for their products. Much of their research is wasted on products that are designed to restart the patent clock.

And then they waste funds on intensive marketing to convince physicians and the public that these more expensive products should be purchased when they are often no better than existing, but less profitable, generic products.

Quentin has been an activist for a national health care system and is now the National coordinator of Physicians for a National Health Program

Downloading patents – Cheaper than music.

Tim Uy at Stanford emailed about his newest venture — onCloud8. You can download patents and applications for 88 cents a pop.

I don’t know how Tim obtains the raw patents data. Those who are planning to download from the USPTO in quantity should beware. I have a friend who set up a perl script to download about 300,000 patents — the USPTO eventually blocked his IP addresses. They have a policy against excessive downloading.

These databases are intended for use by the general public. Due to limitations of equipment and bandwidth, they are not intended to be a source for bulk downloads of USPTO data. Bulk data may be purchased from USPTO at cost (see the USPTO Products and Services Catalog). Individuals, companies, IP addresses, or blocks of IP addresses who, in effect, deny service to the general public by generating unusually high numbers (1000 or more) of daily database accesses (searches, pages, or hits), whether generated manually or in an automated fashion, may be denied access to these servers without notice.

“At cost” may be a bit shocking. For example, 2004 patent application data for 2004 has a cost of $37,800. (Pricelist)

Update: Tim is a graduate student in applied physics, and his data is not coming from the USPTO site. If you have specific requests, he may be able to work with you. email Tim.

Technology Transfer and Assignment via eBay

Here is your chance to purchase all rights to the Pollution-Free Alternative Fuel Moter Conversion Kit invented by Ron Meritt.

Meritt has designed the conversion kit to allow motors to run on either flamable or non-flammable fuels, meaning that a properly converted motor using this technology may run on just about any gas or liquid, including water.

According to Meritt’s website an eBay auction will begin May 10 and run for 10 days with no reserve. The purchaser will receive

pending patents, trade secrets, a fully functioning prototype engine, and all documentation associated with this invention.

I did not find any patents or published patent applications for the alternative fuel technology (either invented by or assigned to Meritt). This likely means that applications were filed within the last 18 months or that the patents were not filed worldwide.

ScreenShot005
According to Jim Mateja at the Tribune, Meritt is the

same man who brought us the portable video players for cars, the one in a backpack that can be lung on the front seat so kids can watch their favorite movies.

Good luck bidding!

Update 5/10/04: Some additional information has been provided at the Meritt website noting that “documents” have been submitted to the USPTO.

It should be noted that the minimum legal documents were submitted to protect the secrecy of this design. The buyer is strongly advised to retain a licensed patent attorney to submit additional legal documents to insure maximum protection for this technology. The buyer understands that from the date of purchase, all future funding for engineering, technology development, legal protection or representation, and any other resource supporting this technology, prototype motor, and/or project is the responsibility of the buyer.

Here is a bio of Ron Meritt.

If you are interested in more environmental law news, Stephen Filler has a nice environmental blog known as Green Counsel.

Reach Through Claims

Basic scientific researchers often file patents with “reach through” claims that attempt to cover treatment of a patent using a drug developed from the researcher’s assay. The University of Rochester’s patent covering Celebrex(r) was found invalid in 2003 after the Federal Circuit held that the written description did not adequately cover the reach through claims. (Case).

In a recent article, BSK offers some advice for capturing the value of basic research. (HTML PDF). Their advice relies on resourceful patent drafting in order to ensure that the written description requirement is satisfied. Alternatively, creative licensing may allow a research institution to link royalties for their new discoveries and assays to successful product development or FDA approval by licensing pharmaceutical companies.

Merrill Goozner has a great post discussing the conflict of interests problems at basic research insitutions (like the NIH) that stem from outside consulting and patenting.

Intellectual Property Task Force

One of my old professors, Jack Goldsmith, has joined the Justice Department’s new Intellectual Property Task Force headed by David Israelite. The task force will reexamine how the DOJ handles IP issues and develop a set of recommendations.

According to Mr. Israelite,

The Attorney General is committed to vigorous enforcement of the law and the protection of intellectual property rights, and those priorities will guide the task force as it seeks to strengthen and improve the Justice Department’s efforts in the intellectual property arena.

Patent Pooling

Richard Gilbert has a new article in the Stanford Tech Law Review discussing patent pooling and antitrust.

There is no simple prescription to determine when a patent pooling arrangement is anticompetitive. . . . Antitrust evaluations should begin with a study of the competitive relationships of the patents involved in the pool. Unfortunately, this is not a simple task. . . . If the pool combines many patents, each of which can block the use of a technology, a challenge to the pool is not likely to affect prices unless all of the blocking patents are shown to be invalid or not infringed.

JuNelle Harris Co-EIC of STLR emailed that they are seeking contributions for their “Perspectives” section:

STLR Perspectives features concise, readable analyses of cutting-edge technology law and policy issues. High quality, law-focused work by scholars, students, practitioners, and advocates is welcomed. Submissions should be no more than 15 pages in length, double-spaced and including footnotes, and will be considered on a rolling basis.