Obviousness is Reviewed De Novo

Muniauction, Inc. v. Thomson Corp. and I-Deal (Fed. Cir. 2008) (Part II)

[Read Part I discussing joint infringement]

Muniauction’s patent relates to municipal bond auctions. During cross examination at trial, Muni’s expert admitted that two of the claims were identical to the prior art except for the patentee’s use of a web browser to access the auction. Despite that admission, the Pittsburgh jury refused to invalidate the patent leading to an award of $77 million for willful infringement. On appeal, the CAFC reversed – finding the claimed invention obvious.

No Obvious Deference: Like claim construction, obviousness is a question of law that is reviewed de novo on appeal. Despite that similarity, obviousness is normally decided by a jury. This difference is justified by the relatively small number of “underlying facts” in contention during claim construction as compared with plethora of factual issues that build up to a conclusion of obviousness. As the CAFC explained in the 2007 Dippin’ Dots opinion, “[t]hose factual underpinnings include the scope and content of the prior art, differences between the prior art and the claims at issue, and the level of ordinary skill in the art.”

Here, the court cited KSR to hold – as a matter of law – that the Muniauction improvement was nothing “more than the predictable use of prior art elements according to their established function.”

Broad Claims Create Trouble for Secondary Factors: Broadly written claims increase the chance that some prior art will be found to invalidate the claimed property right. Here, the CAFC also found that broad claims make it difficult to use secondary factors of patentability to establish nonobviousness. The particular issue here is that a tight nexus must link the claimed invention to the secondary factors (such as long felt need & market success).

“[C]ommercial success or other secondary considerations may presumptively be attributed to the patented invention only where ‘the marketed product embodies the claimed features, and is coextensive with them.'” Quoting Ormco v. Align.

Muni showed success of its products. However, the reports of success focused only on one portion of the invention as claimed. The appellate panel compared those narrow reports of success with the broad claims – finding that the success “lacks the required nexus with the scope of the claims.”

MUNIAUCTION: Joint Infringement Requires Mastermind

Muniauction, Inc. v. Thomson Corp. and I-Deal (Fed. Cir. 2008)

Ray Niro’s team helped Muniauction win a jury verdict of willful infringement resulting in an award of $77 million for lost profit and enhanced damages. On appeal, the CAFC reversed finding some of the claims obvious as a matter of law and others not infringed. As its name implies, Muniauction’s patent relates to municipal bond auctions.

Infringement by a Single Actor: If it were not well understood already, this opinion completely rejects the rogue theory of joint infringement. Rather, a method claim is only infringed when a single party can be charged with performing each step of the asserted claim. Here, Muni’s claims required action by both a bidder and an auction system.

There are times when infringement can be found despite multiple actors. However, in those cases, a single party must be shown to exercise “control or direction” over the entire infringement. This is known as the “mastermind” requirement, and the CAFC has noted that it closely parallels the theory of vicarious liability.

“the control or direction standard is satisfied in situations where the law would traditionally hold the accused direct infringer vicariously liable for the acts committed by another party that are required to complete performance of a claimed method.”

The CAFC left some wiggle room. A later case could still hold that it is not necessary to show facts sufficient to support traditional vicarious liability. (This case notes that such facts would be sufficient, but does not state they are necessary). Thus activities by an independent contractor could potentially still be attributed to the principal. However, the court made clear that direct infringement will not be found when the steps of a method claim are performed “mere arms-length cooperation” between parties. I have suggested that the line be drawn with collusion or conspiracy to infringe rather than limited to principal-agent relationships.

Obviousness: Muni’s expert admitted that claims 1 and 31 were identical to a prior art system except for the patentee’s use of a web browser to access the auction. In a post-KSR world that type of invention is difficult to protect. The court reversed the jury verdict – finding the invention obvious as a matter of law. [More on Muniauction obviousness in tomorrow’s post]

Notes: The non-infringed claim reads as follows:

1. In an electronic auction system including an issuer’s computer having a display and at least one bidder’s computer having an input device and a display, said bidder’s computer being located remotely from said issuer’s computer, said computers being coupled to at least one electronic network for communicating data messages between said computers, an electronic auctioning process for auctioning fixed income financial instruments comprising:

inputting data associated with at least one bid for at least one fixed income financial instrument into said bidder’s computer via said input device;

automatically computing at least one interest cost value based at least in part on said inputted data, said automatically computed interest cost value specifying a rate representing borrowing cost associated with said at least one fixed income financial instrument;

submitting said bid by transmitting at least some of said inputted data from said bidder’s computer over said at least one electronic network; and

communicating at least one message associated with said submitted bid to said issuer’s computer over said at least one electronic network and displaying, on said issuer’s computer display, information associated with said bid including said computed interest cost value,

wherein at least one of the inputting step, the automatically computing step, the submitting step, the communicating step and the displaying step is performed using a web browser.

    

Patently-O Bits and Bytes No. 50

  • Query: Does anyone use the XML links found within private PAIR?
  • Obviousness: Secondary factors are generally used to prove that an invention is nonobvious. Symmetry may cause us to think that factors may also exist that are useful in showing that an invention is obvious. A recent article by Brent Yamashita explores one of these: Simultaneous Invention. “[T]he fact that another person simultaneously and independently created the same invention claimed in the patent-in-suit can serve as an indication that the invention was obvious.”
  • EVENTS:  Upcoming events from American Conference Institute:
  • Patent Lie: I read A Patent Lie over the weekend — lots of fun for a patent attorney to read.
  • Tragedy of the Anticommons: Professor Heller’s new book is apparently an easy read. His work serves as a base for many who see IP rights as excessive and problematic. [LINK][Tim Wu Review]
  • CAFC Leans on District Court to Open Sealed Case

    Kuney v. Bean (BayState v. Bowers) (Fed. Cir. 2008)

    Professor Kuney is in the midst of writing a detailed account of the BayState v. Bowers case file. In that case, the CAFC affirmed the enforceability of a shrink wrap license term that barred reverse engineering of the software. In that case, a number of amici briefs argued that reverse engineering sits at the core of capitalism.

    Like most patent lawsuits, the documents filed and exchanged in the case are kept from the public – sealed under a stipulated protective order signed by the Massachusetts District Court. To open the file, Kuney filed a motion to intervene in the case and to modify the protective order. Bowers agreed to open access to the documents, but Bean (BayState’s successor in interest) initially refused. Although Bean and Kuney later agreed to a modified protective order, the court refused to enter it and rejected Kuney’s motion to intervene.

    On appeal, the CAFC found that the lower court had abused its discretion and vacated.

    Opening a Sealed File: “Intervention is the proper means for a non-party to challenge a protective order.” When making a determination of whether to open records, the courts should begin with “a presumption of public access to judicial records.” In a decade old case, the First Circuit explained the value of public access as fostering “the important values of quality, honesty, and respect for the judicial system.” In this case, the CAFC recognized that Kuney needs the documents to do his scholarly work. However, the district court created no record of weighing the value of public access against the presumption of privacy.

    Because the district court failed to explain its reason for dismissal, this case is vacated “for a balancing of the public and private interests in determining whether to grant or deny Professor Kuney’s motion.”

    Rich Baker Announces Congressional Bid

    Richard Baker is 3Com’s innovative intellectual property director. He is also running for Congress to represent the 6th District of Massachusetts as a Republican. (North of Boston). For many years, Baker has been a proponent of strong patent rights and monetization of those rights:

    “We need strong patent laws in the United States to protect our ideas, to protect our inventors, to protect our jobs, from infringers. For the past several years, many in Congress have been working hard to water down our patent laws, trying to make it easier for copiers to steal ideas. As an Intellectual Property Executive, I know the impact of these changes on the Massachusetts economy, and I will fight efforts to weaken our protection in the global economy.”

    Baker is the republican candidate and will be up against incumbent Democrat John Tierney in the fall.

    Links:

    Business System Patents

    Ex Parte Simpson, Appeal 2008-0569 (BPAI 2008)

    HP’s patent application focused on software used to discover networked devices. Claim 32 was rejected for lack of statutory subject matter.

    32. A device discovery service stored on a computer-readable medium, the service comprising:

    logic configured to discover devices directly connected to a network that are not directly connected to a computer; and

    logic configured to provide a user home service accessible with a network browser with a list of at least one discovered device that is available for use on the network.

    This claim is interesting because like Wasynczuk, it involves a system claim that is not patentable subject matter.

    ‘These claims are directed to a “service” stored on a computer-readable medium, the service comprising logic “configured” to perform functions. Logic, read with reasonable breadth, includes descriptive material indicating the algorithm or reasoning behind an operational computer program, not the program itself. As such the claims are addressed to nonfunctional descriptive material, which is non-statutory. “When nonfunctional descriptive material is recorded on some computer-readable medium, in a computer or on an electromagnetic carrier signal, it is not statutory since no requisite functionality is present to satisfy the practical application requirement.” MPEP § 2106.01.’

    Similarly in Ex parte Godwin (BPAI 2008), the Board found that IBM’s “server system” claims non-statutory subject matter. In that case, the server was recited in the claim preamble and thus non-limiting.

    Apotex Challenge to ACULAR LS Patent Barred by Res Judicata

    Roche Palo Alto and Allergan v. Apotex (Fed. Cir. 2008)

    Roche’s patent covers drug formulations for treating eye inflammation and covers products sold as ACULAR and ACULAR LS. The two formulations differ in their proportion of various drugs such as an ammonium preservative and a surfactant.

    Hoping to sell generic versions, Apotex filed two ANDAs with the FDA – one for each formulation.  In response, Roche filed two separate infringement actions against Apotex (the ACULAR and ACULAR LS cases respectively). In 2007 the CAFC put a final nail in the ACULAR case by affirming the district court’s holding that the patent was not invalid and not unenforceable (infringement had already been decided).  This appeal involves ACULAR LS.

    Reverse Doctrine of Equivalents Remains Dead: In the 1950 Graver Tank opinion, the Supreme Court discussed how the reverse DOE can be used to limit the scope of claim coverage: “where a device is so far changed in principle from a patented article that it performs the same or a similar function in a substantially different way, but nevertheless falls within the literal words of the claim.” Although Graver Tank stands as good law, the CAFC has “never affirmed a finding of non-infringement under the reverse doctrine of equivalents.”  Here, the CAFC continued to reject the doctrine of reverse equivalents.

    Relying on a technical expert, Apotex argued that its formulation – although covered by the literal claims – operated under a different principle (involving the formation of micelles). The CAFC rejected this argument for several reasons: (1) the principle was derived from expert testimony without relying on the prosecution history which was not entered into evidence in the case; (2) the principle was not required in the specification; and (3) there was no evidence that the examiner relied on the principle in allowing the patent to issue.

    Claim Preclusion: Apotex hoped to challenge the patent’s validity a second time — this time with the benefit of the new KSR standards for obviousness. The district court, however, refused a second go-round — finding the claims precluded. In the Ninth Circuit, claim preclusion applies to prevent subsequent litigation where “(1) the same parties … were involved in the prior litigation, (2) the prior litigation involved the same claim or cause of action as the later suit, and (3) the prior litigation was terminated by a final judgment on the merits.”  In patent cases, the second suit is considered the “same claim” when the accused products are “essentially the same.”  The party asserting claim preclusion has the burden of proving that the accused products are essentially the same.

    Essentially the Same: On appeal, the CAFC held that analysis of whether two products are essentially the same (for claim preclusion) should focus on the claims. Here, the court affirmed that both the ACULAR and ACULAR LS formulations are essentially the same “because both formulations are encompassed by the [patent] claims.”

    “Though the court recognized that there are differences in the concentrations of the ingredients in the ANDA-1 and ANDA-2 formulations, it also realized that all of the concentrations are well within the ranges claimed in the ’493 patent. The fact that they are stabilized by different mechanisms, even if true, is irrelevant because both formulations are encompassed by the claims of the ’493 patent. Thus, any difference in composition between the two formulations is merely colorable and the two formulations are “essentially the same.”

    In addition, the CAFC confirmed that there is no “change of law” exception to claim preclusion — what is done is done. Thus, KSR gives no right to re-open closed claims. (*There are of course some exceptions to this role of no exception.).

    Notes:

    • Claim preclusion is also known as res judicata. The CAFC did not need to reach whether issue preclusion should also apply.
    • The CAFC’s claim preclusion jurisprudence appears to be developing a pro-patentee bias. Compare this Roche with the Acumed v. Stryker (a patentee does not lose rights by filing suit against only some of an accused infringer’s products).

    Recent BPAI Decisions

    • Chief Judge FlemmingPrecedential:
    • Ex parte Ghuman, Appeal No. 2008-1175 (BPAI May 1, 2008)(rejected claims that are not appealed are considered withdrawn and subject to cancellation by examiner).
    • Ex parte Fu, Appeal No. 2008-0601, 2008 WL 867826 (BPAI March 31, 2008) (applying KSR to find it obvious to substitute one species for its genus where the genus contains a limited number of species).
    • Ex Parte Nehls, Appeal No. 2007-1823, 2008 WL 258370 (BPAI January 28, 2008) (“substantial” and “specific” utility).
    • Ex parte Letts, Appeal No. 2007-1392, 2008 WL 275515 (BPAI January 31, 2008) (applicant may not conditionally withdraw a claim on appeal).
  • Informative:
    • Ex parte Wasynczuk (BPAI June 2, 2008) (Computer method claims were patentable subject matter because they “recite a process that employs one of the other statutory categories.” On the other hand, the “computer implemented system” claims were not patentable subject matter because they did not recite a “particular machine implementation”.)
    • Ex parte Langemyr (BPAI May 28. 2008) (mathematical manipulations of data do not become eligible subject matter even when performed on a computer and outputted to a display).
    • Ex parte Kim (BPAI May 29, 2008) (indefiniteness rejection affirmed; PTO will not assume a particular meaning of claim terms without some factual or rational basis).

    Patently-O Bits and Bytes No. 49

    • On June 11, 2008, the PTO submitted its “Fiscal Year 2009 Revision of Request for Continued Examination, Eighteen-Month Publication, and Other Miscellaneous Cost-Recovery Patent Fees.” The particulars of this amended proposal have not been released. [LINK]
    • Copyrights may now be registered electronically ($35) [LINK]

    Poor Man’s Opposition at the PTO: Trickery

    Several attorneys relayed their experience with my poor man’s opposition. One gamey approach that is for the third party to hold its prior art materials until the USPTO issues a notice of allowance and then immediately forwards several important references to the patent applicant the case. The patentee can either (1) suffer the delay of withdrawing the patent from issuance in order to have the new art considered or (2) allow the patent to issue while knowing that its duty of disclosure had not been fulfilled.

    Poor-man’s Opposition Proceeding

    Nowotarski and Bakos propose opening the patent prosecution process to third parties – at least to allow some forms of protests or pre-issuance oppositions. Those activities are expressly barred by 35 U.S.C. 122(c). [LINK]

    Although no direct oppositions are available to third parties worried about pending patent applications, an increasing number of attorneys are employing a strategy that could be termed a ‘poor-man’s opposition.’ The round-about strategy relies on the patent applicant’s duty of candor to ensure that opposition materials be submitted to the PTO.

    Poor-Man’s USPTO Opposition Procedure:

    1. Create package of prior art and report explaining why pending claims are unpatentable;
    2. Forward package to attorneys representing patentee with reminder of the duty of candor (retain evidence of submission);
    3. Applicant should submit entire package to PTO;
    4. Monitor PAIR to ensure that examiner receives and uses package;
    5. If necessary provide follow-up evidence and reports.

    If the patent applicant fails to submit either the prior art or the associated reasoning, any issued patent may well be found unenforceable due to inequitable conduct during prosecution. An additional feature of this procedure is that the opposing party can – at its option – remain anonymous. Many attorneys don’t like this process because of the lack of control and because it “shows your hand.”

    Patently-O Bits and Bytes No. 48

    • Judy Jarecki-Black from Merial Limited has been named the “Best Chief IP Counsel” by 2008″ by Global Counsel Awards 2008. Glacéau was awarded the “Best IP Counsel Team.” [LINK]
    • Eastern District of Texas Settlement: SAP agrees to pay $83 million to i2 Technologies. [LINK] In what appears to be primarily a trade secret case, Oracle is seeking $1 billion in damages from SAP. (Oracle’s no-patent strategy may prove successful).
    • Shen Wei v. Ansell Health Care (N.D. Ill 2008) (Claim Construction Issue Preclusion): The patentee lost a claim construction argument in earlier litigation against another party. In this case, Judge Guzman held that the patentee could not re-argue the construction based on collateral estoppels / issue preclusion. [LINK]
    • BPAI Constitutionality Problem: Representative Berman has introduced H.R. 6362 to fix the BPAI judge appointment problem by returning the duty of appointment to the “Secretary of Commerce, in consultation with the Director of the United States Patent and Trademark Office.”
    • No Double Secret Expedited Reexamination: In Reexamination No. 95/008,972 the PTO recently refused to give any preferential or speedy treatment of the reexamination despite pending litigation. [LINK]

    Repeal 35 USC 122(c) …..at least for Business Methods

    By Mark Nowotarski and Tom Bakos

    35 USC 122(c) needs to be repealed and replaced with a law that will allow a more efficient and effective examination process. The current legal requirement to prevent third parties from participating in the patent examination process is no longer in the best public interest. Peer to Patent has shown us that public participation works, but the next step is impossible until 122(c) is at least amended. An examination process that utilizes the expertise of the industries in which applications lie has now become essential in the very difficult to examine fields of software, pharmaceuticals, and business methods.

    35 USC 122(c) was added to the American Inventors Protection Act of 1999 to protect the interests of applicants, particularly small entities, once their patent applications were published. The concern at the time was preventing major corporations from harassing independent inventors by inundating the patent office with submissions and commentary intended merely to delay and ultimately prevent otherwise well deserved patents from issuing.

    Times, however, have changed.

    The USPTO can’t keep up with demand in part because it lacks technical expertise in many fields. A growing public perception is that patents inhibit innovation. The Supreme Court is openly questioning the presumptive validity of business method patents and political forces are aligning themselves to legislatively restrict the scope of patent protection in some of the most promising areas of growth in our economy, such as the financial services sector.

    Recent trials of the Peer to Patent program have shown that well regulated systems for third party submissions and commentary can be set up to effectively assist examiners and dramatically improve the efficiency and thoroughness of patent examination. The system demonstrated its ability to harness the efforts of third party reviewers, including those in the employ of large corporations, to not only uncover important prior art, but to provide useful commentary as well. And, it did this without the feared negative consequences of large corporations unfairly dominating the examination process. But Peer to Patent is of limited use as long as 35 USC 122(c) restricts it to applicants who volunteer to have their applications reviewed and stops the review once the application is in the hands of an examiner.

    Our experience in working together on several business method cases is that the combined efforts of a practitioner (like Mark) and third party technical expert (like Tom) yields dramatically higher quality applications and faster prosecution. We see no reason why the same principles can’t be applied by the USPTO so that examiners, with the proper safeguards, can work with third party technical experts to get higher quality patents to issue in substantially less time.

    Recent advances in the art of public participation in patent examination can be applied to assure that large corporations do not unfairly monopolize third party submissions thus rendering 35 USC 122(c) in its current form no longer necessary. Rather than requiring the Director to block third party submissions, the law should allow the Director to harness the efforts of outside experts in order that inventors can receive the timely and thorough patent examination they deserve.

    • 122(c) reads as follows: “PROTEST AND PRE-ISSUANCE OPPOSITION.- The Director shall establish appropriate procedures to ensure that no protest or other form of pre-issuance opposition to the grant of a patent on an application may be initiated after publication of the application without the express written consent of the applicant.”

    [NOTE: Mark Nowotarski is the president of Markets, Patents & Alliances and is a registered patent agent specializing in business methods. His background is in mechanical engineering and he has 17 patents in this field. Tom Bakos FSA MAAA is an independent actuary specializing in helping clients patent their insurance innovations. He is an inventor on one issued and several pending business method patents. Mark and Tom are also coeditors of the Insurance IP Bulletin. The Insurance IP Bulletin is a bimonthly publication dedicated to helping the insurance industry use patents to promote innovation.]

    Reigniting the Engine of Growth with the Sparkplug of Invention

    By Michael Martin.

    Why do patents end up in litigation? Typically, people answer that it is the amount of money at stake. This answer is not wrong. Since the cost of litigation is relatively constant, people should be (and in fact are) more willing to pay lawyers to litigate claims that are very large compared to the cost of litigation. But this is not a full answer to the question. For this answer does not explain why patents specifically should end up in litigation more often. In fact, trillions of dollars in legal rights are exchanged everyday around the globe without litigation. By comparison, the amount of money at stake in patent lawsuits is relatively small.

    The Theory of Focal Points

    Economist Thomas Schelling is famous for advancing a theory of conflict and cooperation. According to Schelling, even when communication (and hence negotiated agreement) are difficult or impossible, two people can cooperate through a shared focal point. For example, if I told you to meet me in New York City tomorrow but for some reason I couldn’t tell you where and when, we might still meet by going to a famous spot at noon, such as Grand Central Station or the top of the Empire State Building. Our shared vision of these famous spots is a focal point that permits us to coordinate.

    The theory of focal points explains why some groups of people fight and some cooperate. When the focal point for a first group is mutually exclusive to the focal point for a second group, conflict emerges. When the focal point is shared or non-mutually exclusive, cooperation emerges. To some extent, all conflict between people can be viewed as a costly renegotiation of focal points.

    With Schelling’s theory in mind, let’s revisit the question of patents. What are the focal points for the various parties involved in patent litigation? To simplify the question, suppose there are only two groups involved in patent litigation: “inventors” (or their employers) and “producers” (i.e., the people who sell products or services that practice a claimed invention). Ignore for now the detail that some inventors are also producers, and that some producers are also inventors.

    When patents are litigated, the focal point for inventors is on obtaining a large royalty or payment for the right to practice the invention. By contrast, the focal point for producers is on paying a small (or no) royalty or payment to practice the invention. Although both inventors and producers seek profit, at the point in time when patents are litigated, these focal points are mutually exclusive because (at worst) both have incurred costs of R&D for developing the invention. Patent litigation thus becomes a zero sum game.

    The Focal Point of Profit

    At first glance, therefore, one might think that inventors and producers are doomed to conflict. Before rushing to that conclusion, however, it’s worth noting that in some broader sense, at least, inventors and producers share a focal point — namely, profit.

    Profit is an unusually broad focal point. As Adam Smith is famous for pointing out, the voluntary exchange of goods and services creates profit. With profit the focal point, the problem of avoiding conflict between inventors transforms into a problem of identifying and promoting the circumstances in which the voluntary exchange of inventions for cash can take place between inventors and producers.

    If such voluntary exchanges never occurred, we might have reason to doubt whether conflict between inventors and producers could ever be avoided. Fortunately, such exchanges do, in fact, occur. Thus, it can be inferred that the conflict arises over how what is exchanged (services and patent rights) should be valued.

    Again, this might seem puzzling at first because, at least in principle, there should be no difference in how value is measured. At least within the United States, the same rules for accounting and reporting financial statements apply to both inventors and producers. In principle, the inventors and producers should be able to compare their financial statements, and reach some agreement over the value of an invention.

    But since this never seems to occur, the most reasonable inference seems to be that the conflict arises from a difference in how we interpret accounting and financial statements. In fact, it is precisely here that the focal points of inventors and producers diverge. Having had the rare opportunity of working both in patent law and accounting, it has been my privilege to be one of the first to have noticed this. In short, a better theory of accounting would help resolve conflicts over patented inventions and restore a cultural norm of cooperation within patent law. Astute readers should note that, in addition to patent law, Venice was the birthplace of double-entry accounting in the 15th century.

    Problems with the Static Picture of Cost Accounting

    As described by William H. Waddell and Norman Bodek in Rebirth of American Industry, the theory behind the most dominant method of accounting (which is called “cost accounting”) was developed at General Motors in the early 20th century by Alfred Sloan, Pierre DuPont, and Donaldson Brown. The relevant detail about this theory is that it was designed to measure (and hence manage) return on investment (ROI). To that end, the paradigm that Sloan, DuPont, and Brown had in mind in developing their rules for accounting was a static picture. Specifically, their picture was of what the corporation would be worth in liquidation.

    With the picture of the corporation in liquidation in mind, it is easier to understand why so many things that we might intuitively imagine to be costs are instead treated as assets under cost accounting. For example, under the cost accounting system, unsold inventory is reported as an asset. Cost accounting assumes that the inventory could be sold at cost in liquidation. The reporting ignores, of course, the fact that unsold inventory will incur expenses. More importantly, it ignores that what’s unsold before liquidation is less likely to sell at cost in liquidation.

    Under the cost accounting system, IP is called an asset on balance sheets. Again, the assumption is that patents can be sold at cost during liquidation. Again, this assumption begs several important questions. Perhaps most importantly is the question of why, if the IP is so valuable, it could not be used to attract financing or revenue, thereby avoiding liquidation. There were (and are) reasonable answers to that question when debt or equity are unavailable for reasons that have nothing to do with the demand for the patented invention. But its salience suggests that there might be better ways to measure the value of IP.

    Whereas all patents cost something to procure, market demand only emerges for a handful of all patented inventions. Thus, the system of cost accounting has given managers and investors the perverse incentive to aggregate thousands of patents, inflating their balance sheets, much like we saw prior to the subprime mortgage debacle. Firms invest billions of dollars in new technology, spend millions on patent portfolios, inflating their asset accounts — all before attracting a single customer! Not to be outdone, when the corporation fails, the cost accounting system encourages us to sell the patents at auction, and let third-parties extract whatever they can from the legal rights. On my view, the system of cost accounting, coupled with the shortage of patent lawyers who really understand technology, are responsible for the emergence of the worst kind of patent trolls.

    Dynamic Accounting and the Promise of Cooperation

    Fortunately, there is now a light at the end of the tunnel. In fact, many corporations have shifted away from the static picture of corporations inherent in cost accounting to a more dynamic picture. Lean accounting, in fact, was practiced at Ford Motor Company almost 100 years ago, before Ford was eclipsed by the success of General Motors. It turns out that cost accounting is a perfectly fine system of accounting when demand is basically infinite relative to the cost of supply. If the market is never cleared, then the corporations that use cost accounting will end up reporting higher return on investment (ROI) than the corporations that use lean accounting. Lean accounting is an inherently more stable mechanism for promoting growth within a corporation in part because it does not tradeoff short-term gains in income against long-term sustainable growth. But once GM started doing it, everybody else in the automobile industry, and eventually the entire economy, had to follow.

    Under a dynamic theory of accounting, IP is more like equity than it is like an asset. That’s because the primary value of patent rights is in promoting invention and collaboration, both of which are dynamic because people are dynamic. Elsewhere I have explained how inventors are customers. Within the cycle of growth of corporations, inventors and customers are the source of information about demand. It is no accident that unmet need was considered by Judge Learned Hand to be the most important of the secondary considerations on obviousness.

    By contrast, assets are static. By adopting rules for reporting and managing the IP that are more consistent with the actual mechanism whereby it increases profit, we will in turn discourage wasteful conflicts. A very important corollary to this is that stronger patent rights would be beneficial in promoting collaboration and avoiding conflict. Strong property rights discourage people from litigating what could be solved through negotiation at an earlier point in time. As Robert Frost noted, “Good fences make good neighbors.” With a change to the accounting rules, these early negotiations will happen more often.

    Finally, let me emphasize that changes to financial statements need not be dramatic. For example, the simple addition of average daily debit and credit flows for each balance sheet account would permit the shift in managing and investing that I’m advocating here. Since most accounting is now done by computers, this kind of change is actually very cheap. The value of inventions could then be measured easily by comparison between the average daily debit and credit flows before and after an invention had been implemented. Suddenly, inventors and producers have a numerical way to measure the value of an invention.

    [Michael Martin is a former in house counsel and founder of Venetian Capital Management.]

    Will Sprint Communications lead to a rethink of patent law’s standing doctrine?

    By TJ Chiang

    Last week, the Supreme Court decided Sprint Communications Co. v. APCC Services, a case that received more attention for Chief Justice Roberts’ citation to Bob Dylan than the mundane federal jurisdiction issues involved. The case involved the collection of small debts by payphone operators from long-distance phone companies. Because the amounts involved were small, payphone operators assigned their claims to “aggregators,” who effectively brought the suit on their behalf. The issue was whether these aggregators, who had nothing but an assignment of the right to sue the phone companies, had standing in federal court.

    The Court held that “an assignee of a legal claim for money owed has standing to pursue that claim in federal court.” As an example of this longstanding ability to assign legal claims to strangers who had not suffered any personal injury, the Court cited the early patent statute, which permitted (then and now) inventors to assign their patents to others.

    The irony of the shout-out to patent law is that both the Supreme Court and the Federal Circuit have consistently held that the assignee of a legal claim for money owed on a patent does not have standing to pursue that claim in federal court. A bare assignment of the legal claim for past infringement damages—precisely the type of assignment in Sprint Communications, since the plaintiffs were not assigning their payphones to the aggregators—does not confer standing to sue. See, e.g., Crown Die & Tool Co. v. Nye Tool & Machine Works, 261 U.S. 24 (1923); Mars, Inc. v. Coin Acceptors, Inc., No. 07-1409 (Fed. Cir. June 2, 2008). Instead, the assignment must include the patent itself or an exclusive license.

    There are certainly sound policy reasons for requiring the patentee to be a party to an infringement suit, not least because a judgment of invalidity might not be binding absent such participation. At the same time, the patentee standing requirement is a source of frequent litigation at the Federal Circuit. Moreover, because standing is jurisdictional, the issue of proper parties can require an entire case to be relitigated due to a procedural defect. Perhaps the time is ripe for some rethinking in this area, as Sprint Communications and Crown Die appear to be in some tension with each other.

    [NOTE: This summer TJ Chiang is transitioning from his position as an associate at Quinn Emmanuel to become a professor at George Mason Law School. Along with yours truly and Jon Dudas, TJ Chiang is a graduate of the University of Chicago Law School. SSRN]

    Patently-O Bits and Bytes: Conferences

    Recent Patent Law Job Postings:

    Recent Patent Law Job Postings:

    • World Research Group (WRG) is a new media sponsor of the Patently-O Jobs site. July 29-30, WRG is hosting the “5th Annual Conference on Patents and the Financial Services Industry.” They have assembled the top speakers in the industry. [LINK]

    What’s Wrong with Software Patents?

    by James Bessen and Michael J. Meurer

    [This post is the third in a series of posts based on empirical research in a new book, Patent Failure, by James Bessen and Michael Meurer. Read Part I and Part II]

    Patents on computer programs, financial processes and business methods have been controversial at least since the 1960s. Surveys regularly find that computer programmers are opposed to patents on software by a wide margin. In what other field is the class of inventors so opposed to patents?

    Is there a problem?

    Some people contend that there is nothing particularly wrong with patents on software, arguing that "patent thickets" are not preventing innovators from entering software markets. But the latest evidence [LINK] suggests that patent thickets do, in fact, inhibit startups in software. More important, patent thickets might not be the only or even the most important problem with software patents.

    Indeed, our evidence suggests an important problem of another sort: software patents are four times more likely to be litigated than are chemical patents; business methods patents are twelve times more likely to be litigated; finance patents are 49 times more likely. Moreover, the evidence also suggests that these patents have lower values than chemical patents, so these patents are not being litigated more because they are more valuable.

    Other people admit that there are problems with software patents, but they suggest that this is only temporary: once judges and patent examiners understand this technology better, once they have become familiar with the prior art, etc., then the uncertainty about these patents will abate and litigation rates will go down. But the evidence shows that after a decade of issuing software patents in large numbers (over 200,000), the probability that a newly-issued software patent will be litigated is continuing to rise.

    So it does seem that patents on software and related technologies at least have a particular problem with litigiousness. And this problem is central to the poor performance of the patent system generally. In the previous post we highlighted how litigation costs have substantially outgrown the profits that public firms receive from patents outside of the pharmaceutical and chemical industries. In 1999, 38% of the cost of litigation among public firms arose from lawsuits involving software patents; preliminary data suggest that this share has increased since then. Litigation over software patents is clearly a major factor in the poor performance of the patent system. So in a very real way, the overall performance of the patent system cannot be fixed unless the particular problems of software patents are also fixed.

    Why are there so many lawsuits over software patents?

    A variety of evidence leads us to conclude that software patents are involved in relatively more litigation because they are more likely to have "fuzzy boundaries." Statistical evidence shows, for example, that software and business method patents are much more likely than other patents to have their claim construction appealed to the Federal Circuit. Part of this tendency arises because of the nature of the technology and part arises because of the way the courts have treated this technology.

    Our reading of the case law convinces us that patent law tolerates too many software claims untethered to any real invention or structure; in such a world clear boundaries are unattainable. When patent claims relate to actual devices or chemical structures, then their meanings can be interpreted by reference to those physical or chemical entities. However, when the words refer to abstract ideas, they are often subject to multiple interpretations and are therefore more ambiguous. For example, many people thought that "point of sale location" (in the famous E-Data patent) was computer industry jargon for that place in a retail store where transactions take place, formerly occupied by a cash register. When the Federal Circuit interpreted this claim, they decided that it referred to any location where an e-commerce transaction might take place, although it is highly unlikely that this is what the inventor had contemplated 17 years earlier. Thus a broadly worded invention for a kiosk in a retail store was read to cover a broad swath of e-commerce. Not surprisingly, this patent generated quite a few lawsuits.

    Patent doctrines that might serve to prevent such fuzzy claims have been undermined. For example, the enablement doctrine has historically been used to keep patents from claiming much more than what was actually invented. Unfortunately, as a result of Federal Circuit decisions on software patents during the 1990s, these patents no longer need to provide computer code, a flowchart, nor any detailed description of specific operation in order to be enabled.

    Fixing the problem

    A lot of people have very strong opinions about how patent policy should or should not change regarding software patents. We wish we had such clarity, but we do not. We are convinced that the current treatment of software patents creates significant problems and that these are getting worse. But the problem is complex and fixing it will likely involve multiple changes in law and institutions.

    Certainly, KSR should help and so would a stronger indefiniteness requirement. Additionally, it might help to restore a substantial enablement requirement for software patents so that these patents are restricted to claiming more or less what was actually invented and disclosed.

    Possibly, a subject matter test might help. We confess we do not have a rule that cleanly distinguishes inventions using software that should be patentable from abstract processes that should not be patentable. Some people argue that any attempt to proscribe subject matter will only increase uncertainty and encourage avoidance through clever claim drafting. But the evidence suggests that the subject matter tests used following Benson and Flook did not, in fact, encourage excessive litigation during the 1980s, even though there was some evasive claim drafting. Litigation rates for software patents then were about the same as those for all patents. On the other hand, we doubt that a subject matter test by itself would be sufficient to fix the problems of software patents.

    Book Review: Markman at the Beach

    Review by Professor Shubha Ghosh

    A Patent Lie
    A Novel by Paul Goldstein

    For those who are planning a summer trip, especially those IP-geeks who cannot completely get away from work, make sure to pack a copy of Paul Goldstein’s latest A Patent Lie. Like his first novel, Errors and Omissions, published two years ago, this new legal thriller transforms intellectual property practice into a tale of murder and conspiracy.

    I had heard a rumor that Goldstein’s second novel would be about a Markman hearing. Fortunately, the proceeding plays only a small part in the story which involves Buffalo attorney Michael Seeley (referred to as Seeley throughout the book) being called to the Bay Area by his brother to represent a South San Francisco start-up in a patent infringement suit against a Swiss pharmaceutical company. All of this is a routine matter except that previous counsel met an early demise (called a suicide) under a commuter train. Patent litigation often is not a matter of life or death, but adding to the tension is the patent at issue in the case, which covers a treatment for AIDS. But unlike the global corporate conspiracy at the heart of another recent novel dealing with pharmaceuticals, The Constant Gardener, at stake in A Patent Lie are the details of litigation, which rise above the mundane with the personal, political, and professional relationships that Goldstein depicts compellingly.

    At one point in the novel, a character notes that "not only are cases mostly about facts, but no facts are more important than the personalities of the participants." And it is the personalities that drive the story here. Michael Seeley, Goldstein’s protagonist who appeared in the first novel, is the world weary East Coaster, retreating to his home town of Buffalo, New York, to deal with professional and personal crises. The West Coast offers temptations represented here by Seeley’s brother whose involvement in the start-up and the law suit becomes more diabolical by degrees. Temptations also beckon in the character of Lily Warren, a brilliant research scientist who may or may not have been the first to invent the invention in dispute. I doubt that priority disputes have ever taken such inscrutable, or romantic, turns. The law suit takes several twists with an important reversal of interests occurring at the end. Finally, the pushes and pulls on Michael Seeley force him to confront many tensions: his rivalry with his brother, the ethical conundrums of suing a competitor, and the role of a patent lawyer within the patent system.

    The book is a real treat for those who like intellectual property (despite the anti-patent message of the book) and may offer something for the generalist reader who likes to get lost in a legal thriller while basking in the summer sun. After reading Goldstein’s latest, try his first book, which manages to make copyright clearance somewhat riveting. Let me also recommend Killer Smile‘>Lisa Scottoline’s Killer Smile, another legal thriller involving patent law.

    So what will Goldstein’s next thriller be about? Antidilution? Misappropriation? Exhaustion? The Unpredictability of Fair Use? Whatever the topic, I am sure it will add color to the black letter of intellectual property law.

    Patently-O Bits and Bytes: Family News

    • Img058I’m happy to report that my wife gave birth yesterday to a big healthy boy (9 lb 12 oz). We’re calling him Charley after his grandfather who died last June. Most of the posts for the next two weeks will be written by several guest authors. I suspect that you will enjoy the change of pace. On a similar note: For those of you trying to contact me the past few weeks, I apologize for being nonresponsive. Dennis Crouch

    Ron Slusky: Five Prescriptions for Effective Analyzing an Invention and then Claiming It

    PatentLawPic371I asked Ron Slusky to share some insight from his new book on patent prosecution and claim drafting. The book is titled Invention Analysis and Claiming: A Patent Lawyer’s Guide (American Bar Association 2007). [Currently $51 on Amazon] Information about the book, including extensive excerpts, can be found at www.claim-drafting.com

    The following are Slusky’s “five prescriptions for effectively analyzing an invention and then claiming it.”

    1. Identify the inventive concept by beginning from the problem that the inventor set out to solve and then asking how, broadly and functionally, the inventor solved that problem

    The popular alternative approach of drafting a claim of some indeterminate breadth directed to the embodiment(s) and then whittling that claim down will surely result in a broader claim to the embodiment(s) than what one started with. But that approach may still miss the broad invention because if words defining the inventive concept are not present in the original claim—e.g., a new and non-obvious functional interrelationship—such words are unlikely to somehow magically appear during the broadening process.

    2. Begin by drafting a problem-solution statement rather than a claim

    As just noted, drafting claims should not be the primary vehicle for discovering the invention. The structural formalisms of claim drafting, while perhaps familiar and facilitating, can all too easily mislead us into thinking we have discovered the inventive forest when we have actually only identified some of its trees.

    Begin, instead, by drafting a problem-solution statement and use that as the basis for drafting the patent application’s broadest claims A problem-solution statement is a single sentence stating as broadly as possible, but without reading on the prior art, a) the problem the invention solves, and b) the inventor’s solution to that problem. Here, for example, is a problem-solution statement for a seminal invention of rocket pioneer Robert Goddard:

    The problem of enabling a rocket to carry a large amount of combustible material while keeping the weight of the rocket as low as possible is solved by successively feeding portions of the material to the combustion chamber from a separate casing containing the supply of combustible material.

    This leads directly to the following claim appearing in Goddard’s U.S. patent 1,103,503 issued July 14, 1914:

    A rocket apparatus having, in combination, a combustion chamber, a casing containing a supply of combustible material, and means for successively feeding portions of said material to said combustion chamber.

    3. Dream Up Alternatives, Including Some Farfetched Ones

    A powerful tool for analyzing an inventor’s embodiment to extract the inventive essence is to dream up some alternatives to the inventor’s embodiment(s), including some alternatives that are farfetched. These are embodiments that, while outlandish or “wacky,” would nonetheless solve the problem to at least some extent. The more farfetched the better. The point is not to claim, or even to disclose, these embodiments in the patent application. The point is that even a farfetched embodiment can solve the problem without involving some of the implementational details required by practical embodiments. Thus dreaming up farfetched embodiments is a way of isolating the essence of the invention from its illustrative implementational details. Thus, for example, envisioning that a touch-tone telephone might have miniature trained parrots to whistle the various tones might be the key to realizing that the idea of using tones to signal from a caller’s premises to the telephone network was not limited to the use of oscillators and physical push buttons, neither of which are used in, for example, web-based telephony systems like SkypeTM.

    4. Endeavor to discover “What’s Really Going On”

    One way of gaining insight into the breadth of an invention is to ask oneself What’s Really Going On? or—more completely—What’s Really Going On to Solve the Problem? The word "really" in this question emphasizes a search for the fundamental problem and the fundamental solution. What is going on really? The exhortation to discover What’s Really Going On? invites us to exercise our technological curiosity; to dig down and discover what the invention is accomplishing at its essence; to understand what is going on at the 50,000-foot level; to see the invention in terms of fundamental causes and ultimate effects, without all the stuff in between. Thus answering What’s Really Going On? means figuring out—and ultimately claiming—what it is that solves the problem in at least a rudimentary way—not what solves the problem in the most elegant, efficient or commercially attractive way. Indeed, competitors may sacrifice a measure of elegance, efficiency or even commercial attractiveness in their products if it means being able to get into the market or avoid paying a patent royalty. Or they may devise their own elegant, efficient or commercially attractive implementations. Try to identify what is common among all of the embodiments, including some “farfetched” embodiments that the inventor and attorney may be able to collaboratively dream up, as described above. Identifying that which is common to all of those embodiments provides a good start to answering the question “What’s Really Going On?”

    5. Envision the “Opposing Team”—the potential infringer and his patent attorney

    When analyzing an invention and drafting claims based on the analysis, do not focus solely on what the inventor has done. Focus, rather, on what some competitor may do that takes advantage of what the inventor has done while avoiding the claims. The Opposing Team will be poring over the claims after the patent issues, looking for limitations that their product does not meet, or for some way to redesign the product to that end. Thus as each word, phrase and structural element appears on the computer screen, the claim drafter should imagine himself to be the Opposing Team and try to think of a way around that limitation, just like the real-life Opposing Team will do. In short, the patent attorney endeavoring to further his client’s interests is aided in that task by taking on the mindset of a competitor’s attorney endeavoring to further his client’s interests.

    Buy the Book at Amazon or from the ABA.